$Unique_ID{COW03553} $Pretitle{442} $Title{Switzerland 4. The Organisation of Living Conditions: Education, the Economy, Politics} $Subtitle{} $Author{Rene Levy} $Affiliation{Arts Coucil of Switzerland} $Subject{switzerland education political social cantons important state time century swiss} $Date{1986} $Log{Making Bread*0355301.scf } Country: Switzerland Book: The Social Structure of Switzerland Outline of a Society Author: Rene Levy Affiliation: Arts Coucil of Switzerland Date: 1986 4. The Organisation of Living Conditions: Education, the Economy, Politics [See Making Bread: Courtesy Embassy of Switzerland, Washington DC.] a) The Various Sectors of Society The description of how the various tangible and intangible assets which determine the standard of living are distributed has repeatedly demonstrated the fact that these "goods" are produced and distributed within society. The institutions from which they come represent that part of the social structure which has the most direct effect on the living conditions of the individual members of society. Having dealt with living conditions and related inequalities we shall now examine in detail in this chapter and the next the social elements giving rise to these conditions. Social assets are produced and distributed to a large extent within specialised social frameworks, which can be grouped together as sectors characterised by the sort of "goods" they produce and thus by a certain uniformity. Out of these sectors we shall examine education, the economy and politics because they would appear to be especially important from the following points of view: 1) the importance of what they produce and distribute with respect to the daily life of the individual, and 2) their influence on the whole of society. Thus we shall not deal with other sectors, such as the army or religion, or only mention them in passing, such as mass media. We shall only consider certain aspects of the three sectors we have selected, namely those aspects which involve their influence on the situation of the people who live in Switzerland. From this point of view the distribution of social assets is more important than their production, although both aspects are closely linked. In this sense distribution signifies a continual (active) process, whereas in the previous chapter the passive condition which is the result of the active process was meant. It has already been stated that social assets are mainly produced within an organised framework, e.g. in schools, hospitals, factories. This does not apply to the same extent to distribution. Certain social goods are principally distributed on the open market and are therefore in theory available to everyone. But in practice access to this market very much depends on available income and thus on social status. A typical example of a necessity which is distributed on the open market in Switzerland is accommodation. Houses and flats are built by commercial organisations but for the most part sold or rented on the open market. In 1970 only 28% of all families owned their own home (compared to 37% in 1950); the majority of the population lives in rented property. Other assets, however, are mainly available to members of a certain social sector and the higher one has managed to climb in that sector the more one can take advantage of what is available. Education is an example of such an asset. Education is only available to a limited extent on the free market. For the most part it is "obtained" by belonging to an educational institution for a certain time and following a certain course according to that institution's rules. The way in which assets which are valued in a society are produced and distributed within it is an important characteristic of its structure and this factor will affect the continuation or change of that society. Let us now examine these three sectors - education, the economy and politics - and their historical development. b) Education A continual education system, available to all sections of society, was introduced in Switzerland only after the beginning of the 19th century. Earlier there had been hardly any official regulations and education had been provided by the church. For a long time the main subject taught was religion, and such things as reading, writing and arithmetic were only taught at a few urban institutions which were attended by the sons of the wealthier families. A consequence of the Enlightenment was the philanthropist education movement, which reached Switzerland partly via Germany. The ideas propounded by this movement gradually led to concrete results at the beginning of last century, when Switzerland, in the wake of the French Revolution, laid the foundation stone for a standardised school system. The famous educationalist, Pestalozzi, was one of the members of this movement. It was at this time that most cantons introduced general compulsory schooling. Geneva was the only canton which had taken this step earlier (in 1536, during the Reformation), in fact long before it joined the Swiss confederation. The education system continued to undergo changes during the Swiss Restoration (1815-1830). The schools were secularised, i.e. removed from the influence of the church; teaching became a profession and many private schools were founded, in turn stimulating the state policy of education. The Swiss universities were also founded in the 19th century; only the University of Basle dates from the late Middle Ages (1460). The universities were often based in fact on Faculties of Theology, especially in the French-speaking part of Switzerland. After the new constitution came into force in 1848, according to which education was the responsibility of the cantonal authorities, each canton introduced its own laws in this respect. Under the revised constitution of 1874 the cantons had even more sovereignty in matters of schooling. An important new characteristic which developed at this time of fundamental change in education policy was the aim of schooling, which was to "educate the children of all classes of society, according to common principles, to become spiritually active, socially productive and morally religious people", as the canton of Zurich's Education Act of 1859 puts it. According to the ideology of the rising middle classes all children would receive the same education and their progress thereafter would no longer depend on social status but solely on individual achievement. Schools were considered to be sources of ethical education, where moral and political values were emphasised as much as knowledge and achievement. Furthermore education was to be all-embracing, an education of the body as well as the mind. One of the most noticeable characteristics of the Swiss school system is the extent to which the cantons are independent in matters of education policy. Although the responsibility of education has been handed over to the state, this was at a cantonal and not a national level. The federal authorities have in fact had a limited degree of influence on standardising education throughout the country, but only in an indirect way, for example by introducing a state examination in medicine and national recognition of the matura (the equivalent of A-levels). The result of all this is that there are as many different school systems in Switzerland as there are cantons. At each level a large variety of material is used for the same subjects, there are enormous differences in the examinations set and the grading systems, and the academic year does not even begin during the same season in all parts of the country. There are, however, some trends which are common to education throughout the country. Since the middle of the 19th century much more emphasis has been given to quantitative and qualitative expansion. Let us just mention two of the many consequences of this expansion policy: before the turn of the century, the new conscripts from the poorer cantons produced much worse results in the recruitment examinations than those from richer cantons where the level of education available was higher. (The federal authorities introduced these examinations in order to check whether the cantons were fulfilling their obligations as regards education). After the turn of the century this relationship between examination results and the wealth of the canton of origin was no longer obvious because education during the compulsory period was to some extent standardised. A second, less obvious effect of education is the fall in the birthrate, which can be more or less directly linked to the expansion of the educational system and thus the birth rate fell first in those cantons which were more progressive. Further developments include compulsory schooling being extended from 8 to 9 years, the expansion of vocational and secondary school facilities, decentralisation in these institutions and expansion in university education (as already described in Chapter 3). Payment of compensation and graduated grants are aimed to ensure that students from cantons without their own university can enjoy the same educational opportunities as students from cantons having a university. At all levels the number of people to be educated and the number successfully finishing some sort of education have in reality increased. There is, however, a strong correlation between the financial strength of any one canton, the grants it awards and the number of university students per 100,000 inhabitants. The same correlation can be seen regarding the proportion of females among children leaving school with the "matura" and among students. Today the Swiss education system has still not fulfilled its original aim of ensuring the same opportunities for all strata of society. For many decades the proportion of working-class university students has fluctuated at around 5% and the mainly quantitative programme of expansion described above has had very little effect in altering the degree of inequality in educational opportunities for the poorer and the wealthier sectors of society. This problem is even more acute for children of foreigners working in Switzerland. Vocational training is still based very much on the principle of a trade apprenticeship. This apprenticeship is normally done in a firm and is thus controlled by the economy and designed to meet the economy's needs to a greater extent than it would be if it were organised by a school, despite the fact that an increasing number of higher technical colleges have been founded in recent years. For a long time the expansion of the education system was more or less independent of economic change. But since the 1940s state schools have been brought more into line with the aims of the economy and influenced by economic change. However, the school system does not seem to react very rapidly in a quantitative way to such demands: Switzerland still imports specialised knowledge not only in the form of patents but also in that she employs foreign specialists whose level of qualification is rising constantly. For example in 1970 10.3% of technical draughtsmen, 22.9% of highly qualified employees in technical fields and as many as 30.8% of technical graduates were foreigners. It has already been established that the extension of compulsory schooling, the expansion of secondary and higher school facilities and the provision of such facilities in areas previously lacking them have led to an extension of the "interim period" for young people and to an increase in the number of young people in this phase. At the same time the level of education of the younger section of the population is gradually rising and certain inequalities in education are being ironed out (at least inequality between boys and girls and between poor and wealthy areas). These developments are not principally due to a change in individual behaviour, for example increased demand for education, but rather to decisions governing the modification of the organisational structures which provide education. Such influences are partly political such as the composition of school curricula or the fixing of expenditure on education (the latter rose considerably after the Russians surprised and impressed western Europe by getting their "sputnik" into orbit in the late 1950s; expenditure on education is now being reduced). Sometimes, however, these influences come directly from the economy, for example through more apprenticeships being offered in expanding branches such as trade and commerce or the machine industry than in branches which are losing business or going over to a high degree of automation. The education system is also influenced to a lesser extent by plebiscites, as for example in 1973, when a bill concerning the "right to an education", which should have been guaranteed by the confederation, was rejected in a popular vote. c) The Economy 1. The Industrial Revolution The importance of the economy is not only the fact that it turns out producer and consumer goods; it also provides a framework for employment and thus represents the main source of income for the majority of the population. It is therefore impossible for most people to avoid belonging to this social sector, and the economy is thus of the utmost importance both for the individual and for society as a whole. Some of the prerequisites of industrialisation in Switzerland and of the newer developments in her economy have already been described above, as have some of the factors which have brought about changes in working conditions. How did industrialisation come about in Switzerland and what social impact did it have? The relative rapidity with which the Swiss economy moved into the industrial age in the first 30 years of the 19th century was favoured by the prior existence of certain conditions, including the fact that Switzerland was one of the busiest trading countries in Europe in the 18th century. Thus the industrial revolution in Switzerland consisted to a great extent of mechanising the existing industries; the social revolution involved came about more slowly. According to a contemporary estimate, which must be considered exaggerated, before the end of the 18th century roughly two-thirds of the rural population in Switzerland were no longer making a living in agriculture but in crafts and trades and in the earlier forms of industry. In 1800 the official figure for the proportion of workers engaged in crafts and trades was a little over 25%. First of all two pre-industrial manufacturing branches developed quite independently of one another and they were both aimed principally at the export market. The first was the watch-making industry, which started in the 17th century in Geneva and then spread to the higher valleys in the Jura. The second was the textile industry, which was already well established in eastern Switzerland (in the cantons of Zurich and St. Gall) and later spread to such places as Fribourg. Apart from cloth - first wool and linen, and later silk and cotton - the textile factories also started producing more and more high quality finished articles, such as silk ribbon, embroidery and printed fabrics. For a long time Swiss products in these two branches led the international market. It is estimated that in the 18th century about 90% of the world market for watches and clocks was covered by Swiss products. In the 15th and 16th centuries St. Gall was the centre of the European linen trade. While no great changes were introduced in the watch industry until towards the end of the 19th century, the textile industry was developing rapidly, mainly because of increased pressure from international competition. On the one hand the firms started expanding early and mechanising, which led to reductions in the normal outworker system, threatened the income of these workers and, as in other countries, resulted in a public reaction against machines (e.g. the burning of the Uster factory in 1832). On the other hand, three ancillary branches soon developed into industries in their own right: the machine and electrical industries were well established by the end of the first decade of the 19th century, and the chemical industry by the second half of the same century. The machine industry was especially boosted by the construction of the railways, which in its turn had been helped among other things by the fact that under the federal constitution of 1848 cantonal and local tolls were abolished and trade was thus stimulated. The development of the railways led to expansion in banking and later insurance, because the previously existing forms of finance were not sufficient to cope with the new projects. The enormous development in industrial production methods also had an effect on other parts of the economy. Industry employed a growing proportion of the population. At first this was counterbalanced by a drop only in the number of people employed in agriculture, because there was a considerable increase in the population at the same time: between 1800 and 1900 the population of Switzerland doubled. Another reason for this rapid increase in population was that before the Treaty of Vienna in 1815 Switzerland had for many centuries been the most important European source of mercenaries and this demographic safety valve was closed once and for all under the terms of the Treaty. As a result of industrialisation the services sector also began to expand because more and more aspects of trade, transport and also the administration of funds were not dealt with by the manufacturers or the entrepreneurs but handed over to specialised firms. The proportion of people employed in agriculture started to fall at an early stage, although the decrease was slow at first and accelerated after the mid-1800s. Industrialisation and the new and clearly successful ideas concerning business, which were an essential part of it, also stimulated reform within agriculture. More thought was given to profitability and production started to be planned in the strictest sense. Important innovations regarding such things as the three-field system, planted pasture-land, the cultivation of potatoes and systematic manuring had actually already been introduced in the 18th century. As a result of the French Revolution and the centralised state of Switzerland imposed by Napoleon, Swiss farmers too were given equal political rights and freehold rights to the land they worked, although they often ran deep into debt owing to the compensation they had to pay. An important characteristic of Switzerland is the decentralised settlement pattern, which affected the fundamental changes of the 19th century and also contributed to the lack of major conflict between workers and management. Before the industrial revolution only a small proportion of the Swiss population lived in towns. However, in 1875 still only approximately 10% of the population lived in the 12 towns which had more than 10,000 inhabitants. The economy and the social structure of these towns were still very much influenced by the system of guilds, which had developed over many centuries. The guild rules limited trading possibilities for the middle classes to such an extent that new industries were set up mainly in rural areas, especially in eastern Switzerland, where other advantages were to be found, in particular cheap labour and abundant local water-power. For a long time the textile industry in eastern Switzerland employed principally outworkers, who were at the same time farmers and did not go to work in factories. The watch industry in the Jura ran on the same principle. Thus when this type of work was replaced by factory work the decentralised network of small-holdings remained and many former outworkers went to work in the factories but at the same time continued to farm on a small, subsistence scale. In this way their life-style was completely different from that of the plain factory workers who lived in urban blocks of flats. It was the major economic crises at the end of the 19th century and the beginning of this century which led to massive concentration trends, including a greater concentration of people in the towns. 2. Restructuring Concentration and restructuring are the two key-words for the several waves of change which the Swiss economy has gone through since the beginnings of industrialisation. Restructuring firstly in that the proportion of people employed in agriculture fell steadily in comparison with the number of workers and the total value of the goods produced. In contrast the number of workers engaged in industry steadily rose to a maximum figure of 49% in 1963-64. Since then the percentage has been falling slightly, while the percentage of people employed in service industries has continuously risen. In 1971 it exceeded those employed in industry and is now over 50%. A different kind of restructuring has become apparent recently, and is probably only just beginning. In industry those branches and departments concentrating on research and development or highly specialised products which demand highly qualified work and major investment have been expanding. At the same time, apart from expansion in certain public services (schools, hospitals, administration), there has been considerable development in those sections of the services sector which provide administrative, advisory and management services for other firms. 3. Concentration The concentration of the economy happened in several waves and affected all sectors, including agriculture. This sector became highly mechanised a long time ago, thereby saving labour and labour costs. Farmers did become entrepreneurs, but not employers; the family "business" is still the rule in farming. Thanks to mechanisation the productivity level of Swiss agriculture has risen enormously, and despite a considerable overall drop in the number of people employed in agriculture (in 1800 65% of the working population were involved in farming, in 1900 30% and in 1980 only 7%) the level of national self-sufficiency has in fact risen. It varies considerably according to the product but the overall figure is 65% of the calory value of products consumed. This development has caused the farmers to get into debt to such a degree that they are among the highest debtors in the world (per farm and per acre) and this situation is getting no better. At the same time the means of production have become concentrated; in 1876 only 2.2% of all cattle-farmers owned more than 20 head of cattle, whereas in 1973 this figure was 42%. However, over the same period the number of cattle-farmers fell by one third. (The same has happened as regards the amount of land cultivated per farm). Agriculture is the subject of a complicated state protection policy which includes price guarantees and various types of subsidies. Over the past few decades the farmers have only been able to survive despite their debts because they could take advantage of interest-free or low-interest state loans. The degree of concentration of the economy and thus also of potential means of influence available to employers is far greater in other sectors. For example the ten largest firms in the metal and machine industry employ 29% of all workers in this branch. With very few exceptions they are all multinational companies which manufacture a large part of their products outside Switzerland; 62% (i.e. 177,000 people) of their total number of employees work outside the country. Nevertheless medium-sized and small firms are relatively common and are either contracted suppliers to larger firms or independent suppliers of specialised goods or services; these firms also act partly as a buffer in times of economic crisis. For an example of concentration in the services sector let us look at banks. The Swiss banking system is very diverse in its composition and comprises, 1,644 institutions at present. It is, however, dominated by two types of institutions, at least from the point of view of the proportion of the total value of the balance-sheets; these two lobbies comprise 29 cantonal banks and 5 major private banks. Both types of institution originate basically from the last century but have developed in opposite directions. The value of the balance-sheets of the (publicly owned) cantonal banks, the largest of which are almost as important as the (privately owned) major banks, has fallen from 39.5% (1945) to 21.7% (1980) of the total value, i.e. by almost half, while the proportion ascribed to the major banks has doubled, from 25.1% to 51.3%. The banks have expanded enormously over the past few years, at the same time gaining much influence in other parts of the economy, either as lenders, through direct membership of administrative boards or as trustee representatives for large capital shares. The concentration trend is not only resulting in the massing of economic power in specific branches, but is also having serious consequences in other areas, such as the press. In 1939 there was a total of 406 different newspapers in Switzerland, a country which has always been renowned for its choice of newspapers. In 1979 there were only 293, more than 25% fewer. At the same time, however, the circulation of the surviving newspapers rose by 58%. In 1975 the 10 largest newspapers in Switzerland covered 45% of the market. These changes, mainly due to mergers, have resulted in a major shift in political alignment in the press. Amongst the smaller newspapers there is a variety of political tendencies, for although the majority are conservative, there are also left-wing and independent newspapers to be found. There is a paucity of left-wing publications among those newspapers with a medium circulation (20,000 to 50,000), the proportion of independent papers being strong in this range. Amongst those newspapers with a high circulation the independent ones play a leading role. Recent experience has shown that this development is problematic politically in as far as these papers have to be very considerate of people who use their pages for advertising. For this reason their leading position might well result in their definite political stands having increasingly limited chances of being published. Another characteristic of the Swiss economy is the large number of cartels which exist. Through agreements made between the leading firms in any one branch concerning price maintenance, delivery conditions, division of the market according to areas and other criteria, these cartels cover the market in almost every type of product. Switzerland has one of the highest proportions of cartels and freely set prices, not controlled through any agreement, are an exception. We shall not discuss here whether this is advantageous or disadvantageous to the national economy. There is, however, no doubt that apart from signifying a concentration of trade, it is also another indication of the widening gap between the manufacturer's power and that of the consumer. 4. Employer and Employee The stormy economic progress of the 19th and to a certain extent the 20th centuries also had its reverse side from the social point of view. In the 19th century, especially between 1840 and 1860, there was continual unrest due to virtual mass poverty. Before this period there had even been a famine (1816/17), when for example in the canton of St. Gall about 4% of the population died of hunger. For a long time the characteristics of working life were child labour (up until 1842 almost half of the people employed in the cotton industry in Zurich, for example, were children; in the whole of Switzerland this figure was still 10.5% in 1911), an extremely long working day, poor working conditions and insufficient protection against accidents and industrial illnesses. Switzerland was one of the first countries where official measures were taken and laws passed to protect the worker and improve his conditions of employment. The first law on the protection of children to be passed in Europe came into force in the canton of Zurich in 1815; according to this law the minimum age for employment was 10 and the maximum working hours per day were 12-14. The first Factory Act was passed in the canton of Glarus in 1864. However, it must be pointed out that effective measures against impoverishment, unemployment and health risks were only achieved after a long period of class conflict which culminated in the General Strike of 1918. In 1877 a doctor estimated the life expectancy of various sections of the population as follows: for metal workers 35, for the wealthy middle classes 55 and for clergymen 64. The most important economic lobbies had already been formed during the 19th century, after freedom of association had been introduced under the terms of the federal constitution of 1848. The order in which they were founded is significant. After the workers' educational organisations came the first political pressure group in 1870: the Swiss Association of Trade and Industry. Nine years later, in 1879, the members of the various trades formed the Swiss Trades Federation and the workers formed the Swiss Federation of Trade Unions (1880), both organisations being on a national scale. In 1897 the farmers joined to form the Swiss Farmers' Association. It was only after the turn of the century, in 1918, that the white-collar workers founded a real socio-political organisation for themselves. The Association of Trade and Industry, which is still one of the most powerful interest groups today, was founded mainly to represent the interests of the employers against the federal state (for example with the aim of getting protective customs duties introduced), while the Federation of Trade Unions saw itself right from the start as representing the workers against the employers. The Social Democrat Party also dates from this period (1888), and until after the second World War its policies centred around class differences. After the Metal-Workers' and Watch-Makers' Union had been founded and before the first World War, Switzerland experienced its first major strike, and in 1908 the Central Federation of Swiss Employers' Organisations was founded, as a counterpart to the Federation of Trade Unions. After the first World War and the General Strike various measures were introduced aimed at protecting the workers and the latter were also able to take advantage of the general economic expansion. The relationship between labour and capital was to an increasing extent governed by contracts, which often had to be fought for through strikes and lockouts. The employers were very slow to recognise the Unions as negotiating and contracting partners. In 1937 a "peace agreement" was signed by the Metal-Workers' and Watch-Makers' Union, under the terms of which negotiations were to be the basis for introducing changes and both sides were forbidden to use force. Since then relations between the Unions and the employers have been characterised by a policy of negotiation favoured by the economic boom of the 50s and the 60s, within whose framework there has been a predominantly moderate attitude on both sides aimed at encouraging economic progress in production. This attitude is also partly responsible for the high investment rate in Switzerland (over a quarter of the gross national product is invested). Despite the poverty experienced by the working class in the 19th century the workers' movement was weaker in Switzerland than in other European countries; it only became a radical organisation at the turn of the century. This may well be due to a great extent to the decentralised economic and settlement structure, which we have already discussed above, which prevented workers rushing to the fast growing towns. For a long time industry relied on the "farming factory workers", who worked in the factories and at the same time carried on farming their land at subsistence level. Even today there are no big industrial cities in Switzerland comparable to those in other industrialised countries. At the present time the proportion of workers who belong to a union or some other similar organisation is estimated at a third of the gainfully employed population of Switzerland and is thus one of the lowest in Europe. This is no doubt an important factor contributing to the willingness of the Swiss trade unions to settle differences by negotiation. The relative insignificance of the unions may well have added to the fact that even during the economic boom salaries never rose as much as productivity and profits. 5. Economic Development and Employment As in the case of the education system, a breakdown of the important structural changes in the Swiss economy reveals factors which have a direct influence on working conditions for employees. In order to be able to appreciate the extent of this influence, let us summarise the most fundamental changes: - Changes in the structure of production: change from outworker system to factory production, involving a reduction in work volume for outworkers and the introduction of factory work with fundamental consequences as regards the social position of workers' families (child labour outside the home, loss of simultaneous agricultural source of income and consequently more direct dependence on the well-being of the factory, etc.). At the same time increasing shift of production and employment from independent craftsmen into the factory. - Drastic fall in the number of people employed in agriculture (farmers, farm-hands, family helpers) and generally in the proportion of the population living in rural conditions. - Increase in the number of people employed in industry until the middle of the 20th century, followed by decrease. - The fall in employment in agriculture, the transfer of work into the factories and the merging of these factories into increasingly large companies lead to an enormous drop in the number of self-employed workers; by far the largest part of the working population is salaried. - Slightly staggered, continual growth in the services sector; increased polarisation of work into unskilled routine jobs on the one hand and highly skilled, specialised jobs on the other; at the same time the job market is becoming increasingly unsafe, especially for the "fringe" workers, such as older people, women, youths and foreigners. - A further trend should be mentioned, although it is difficult to find an "objective" indication of its existence: the increasing pressure of production, resulting in stress, felt by employees in every branch and at every level, which can be seen in the spread of job and work evaluation systems. This pressure is an individual burden which increases as working hours are reduced. The families of employees are also affected as they become more and more a "place" where the breadwinner recuperates from the pressures of work and thus have to adjust to needs which may easily conflict with those of other members of the family (especially children and wives). - The concentration of far-reaching powers among the largest firms in various branches and thus also at increasingly high levels leads to a growing social gulf between those who have these powers and those who are affected by them. More and more workers are affected by decisions which are taken in circles far removed from their own daily experience, decisions taken on the basis of criteria which are often way beyond their own field of comprehension and which are for them increasingly unfathomable and arbitrary. - Since this concentration is mainly on a legal and organisational level and only leads to very limited expansion in the individual plants, the traditional imbalance between labour and capital is becoming more exaggerated. While the unions' membership only represents a limited part of the work-force, owing to the continued decentralised pattern of employment opportunities and the increasing hierarchical subdivision according to branches, the employers have for many decades been well organised and in a position to realise their aims. d) Politics The most easily visible, organisational framework for the political field of social activity is the state. However, politics are not limited to the state: apart from parliament, the government and the civil service, the political parties and especially the lobbies also play an important role. Politics and the state are important first of all because they, too, produce assets which society desires or at least they guarantee the financial and organisational side of the production and distribution of such assets, examples of which include state education, the administration of justice, public transport, part of the health service, social security and many other state services. The state is moreover a section of society in which tension and conflict arising in other sections are acted out or at least controlled according to more or less clearly set out rules. It is because of this dual role that politics are important in the analysis of the social structure of Switzerland. Like her education system and her economy, Switzerland's political organisation is a product of the 19th century, still showing traces of a more distant history and evidence of more recent changes. Up until the French Revolution there was no state of Switzerland as such but a loose federation of cantons which were completely independent and not bound by the decisions taken by the coordinating body. Furthermore, the members of this confederation did not have equal powers; within the core of the 13 original cantons there were those which held a dominant position, such as Zurich and Berne, and those which were virtually powerless, such as Glarus. There were allied members who enjoyed limited rights, such as the cantons of St. Gall and the Grisons. Finally there were colonies or dependencies which were ruled by other cantons alone or jointly; thus the canton of Vaud and Western Argovia belonged to Berne, while Thurgovia and the Southern Tessin were so-called "common dominions". This interwoven and hierarchical political structure was controlled to a large extent by the rich aristocrats and patricians in the cantonal capitals, which exploited the rural areas through a system by which the latter provided troops of mercenaries against payment of compensation by the cantonal government, as well as through many obligatory payments. In this way the up-and-coming middle classes were not left very much leeway for business in the towns or in the country. This situation changed in 1798 when the French army invaded the canton of Vaud and occupied Berne after a short battle. In many places the French were welcomed as liberators and not considered conquerors at all. It is estimated that 7,000 trees were erected at this time, as symbols of deliverance from the oppressor. This was the start of a long period of political turmoil: Napoleon proclaimed a national constitution along French lines, whereby all parts of Switzerland were equal but at the same time reduced to simple boroughs of a centrally organised satellite state, dependent on France. This Republic of Switzerland imposed from outside was largely incapable of functioning, and after many attempts at revising its form, it was finally abandoned in 1803 through Napoleon's Mediation Act which provided for a confederation of states based on the American model, where the individual interests of each canton could be better taken into account. This system worked well until Napoleon's fall, and in 1815, after the Vienna Settlement, it was replaced by a cantonal alliance, the cantons remaining equal but being completely autonomous in their internal affairs. A Restoration movement developed between 1815 and 1830 and succeeded, especially in the catholic cantons of central Switzerland, in bringing the former patricians and their political organ, the conservative movement, back to power. Political rights were once again reserved for the wealthy and the long-established families. In the canton of Argovia, for example, only those men who possessed more than S.F. 200 in real estate could vote; in Lucerne 20 out of the 36 members of the town council, who were all elected for life, were patricians, and of them 14 were related to each other. The rising middle classes and their political representatives, the liberals and the radicals, were calling for a broader democratic system and it was only possible to suppress their demands for a short time. After 1830 there came a new period of regeneration, especially in the protestant cantons. In 1848, after a short civil war and after the separatist movement of the catholic, conservative cantons had been put down, the Swiss confederation came into existence; despite the far-reaching autonomy enjoyed by the cantons, a strong central government was formed. This state was created out of the political and military victory won by the liberals and the radicals, and it was these groups which dominated parliament for several decades because, among other things, all seven members of the government, elected on a basis of majority rule, came from among their ranks. This period is popularly known as the rule of the economic and political "barons". These barons included prominent entrepreneurs such as the industrialist Alfred Escher, who not only led the industrial canton of Zurich politically for many years, but also played an important role in federal politics. The newly formed democratic movement objected to this situation, and their demands met with such strong support among the population that the federal constitution had to be totally revised in 1874. The introduction of broader political rights at a cantonal and federal level (referendums and initiatives) put an end to the domination of the entrepreneurs and their political representatives. The constitution of 1848 had already placed the state above the church; according to the revised version of 1874 religion was a private matter for the individual, monasteries were taken over by the state, religious orders were forbidden and various other anticlerical measures were taken which brought the conservative movement and the catholic cantons in opposition to the new state. It was only after a hard struggle for secularisation of the state that the radicals, the democrats and the conservatives reached a point of reconciliation in 1891. As confirmation of this, the first conservative was elected to the government. In the meantime those sections of the population who had gained less from the industrial revolution, i.e. the farmers and the workers, started organising themselves. However, they were not able to gain any political power in the federal state until after proportional representation had been introduced (after the General Strike of 1918). The first elections held according to the new principles in 1919 brought fundamental changes to the political composition of the Swiss parliament: the former radicals and democrats (who had by then merged to form the Liberal Democratic Party) lost 45 of their 105 seats, the Social Democrats doubled their number of seats to 41 and the farmers obtained their first 30 seats. Only the proportion of conservative Members returned remained approximately unaltered. Since 1919 the proportion of seats held by the various parties has hardly changed. In 1943 the Social Democrats, who had gone from strength to strength, gained their first government seat and in 1959 their second. As in the case of the conservatives before them, the integration of the Social Democrats into the federal parliament has led to a wave of political moderation, despite the fact that they only have a limited influence on the political decisions they help to take. There is no doubt that the new federal state endorsed the autonomy of the cantons in certain areas, such as education. But at the same time it did away with important barriers, especially economic barriers, between the cantons and made way for more individual freedom for every member of society, which was essential for the development of enterprise: equal political rights for all male citizens regardless of property and titles, freedom of trade, freedom of movement, abolition of road and bridge tolls, common currency (only through this measure did Switzerland become a single economic unit), equality of all citizens before the law and freedom of association. The predominance of free rights and the lack of privileges express quite clearly the ideals which were the aim of the founders of modern Switzerland: the central government should above all guarantee 1) the abolition of the restrictions imposed on the people by the Ancient Regime, and 2) the protection of individual freedom against encroachment by the state itself. In particular the state should ensure free development of the economy, without intervening in that domain itself. However, after only a short time the central authorities had to deal with quite different demands. On the one hand, during the agricultural crisis in the 1870s industry and agriculture, which were under pressure from international competition, started calling for a federal policy of protection. On the other hand, the trade unions and the socialists demanded protection for the workers from exploitation and poverty. Since those days the state, which was originally weak from the organisational and financial points of view, has had to take over more and more responsibilities and has been granted, against strong opposition, a gradually increasing budget. However, national expenditure as a proportion of the gross national product is only 30% (excluding social security), which is the lowest in the world, despite the fact that it has increased considerably in recent years. The state's controlling, compensatory and surrogate functions are distributed very unevenly at the principal levels of political organisation (federal, cantonal, municipal). Federal functions have increased in particular in economic affairs, which means for example that the largest increase in personnel in the civil service departments has been in Finance, Customs and the Ministry of Economics. Federal expenditure represents 40% of all public expenditure, that of the cantons and the boroughs being each 30%. Federal subsidies and their legal share of federal taxes are important financial sources for the cantons and the boroughs, providing up to 50% of the total income of the poorer cantons. Subsidies make up about one quarter of the federal budget and have a certain compensatory effect, in other words if no subsidies were granted the rich cantons would be richer and the poor cantons would be poorer. There is also a certain degree of compensation achieved by the state as regards individual incomes. Since today the state encroaches in many different ways upon the lives of people living in Switzerland, either by dictating, demanding or supporting, the question of how political decisions are taken is of great importance. First of all it should be established that through the system of referendums and initiatives the Swiss electorate does have the final word in many matters. However, in practice only the most influential movements succeed in running a political campaign with the necessary funds, and initiatives are very rarely a direct success. Furthermore, not all important matters are voted on by the electorate, and plebiscites are prepared and evaluated by political groups which can have a strong influence on the options put to the vote. Let us now consider which are the most important lobbies. This question can be answered firstly through the institutional structure of the state; for the sake of simplicity we shall only consider the federal state, which is based on the principle of the separation of power. The 246 Members of both houses are elected every four years; the Members of the "Nationalrat" (comparable to the American House of Representatives) are elected on a basis of proportional representation, and the Members of the "Standerat" (comparable to the American Senate) are elected by majority vote. The two houses together then elect from among their Members the seven ministers who form the government. The two houses, being the legislative body, form the most open arena of political opinion, while the government is the executive body. Although it is only partly representative of effective expression of popular interests let us quickly look at the social composition of the legislative body. According to the system of election currently used the composition of both houses corresponds to the opinions of the voters as expressed at the polls, and in this respect this body is representative. However, from their social characteristics, the Members elected do not appear to be representative of the whole population of Switzerland. This is not surprising but it has, however, an influence on the activities of parliament. First of all there are no foreigners in the two Houses, although about 15% of the population of Switzerland are not of Swiss nationality. There are very few female Members (roughly 10%). Most of the Members have a university degree and approximately half of them are in the professions. The age structure of parliament is also different from that of the population as a whole: only about 10% of the Members are under 40 years of age. Only the two national religions and the three most important national languages are proportionally represented in parliament. This comparison gives only a limited amount of information about the social origins of the people who run the country, because the political exercise of power is not so closely linked to the institutional structure of the state. Out of the 300 or so people who influenced the most important decisions taken in federal politics between 1971 and 1975 only 15% were members of parliament. The rest were representatives of political lobbies (37%), ministers and top people in the civil service (25%), cantonal politicians (19%) and experts (4%). The differences between the broad mass of the public and the small circle of people who take political decisions are even bigger than those which emerge from the comparison with the legislative body. Here it is not only the foreigners, women and the younger generation which are very much under-represented, but also the workers and the political left. In contrast the groups over-represented include university graduates, professional politicians and officers. The large proportion of professional politicians, especially the representatives of the trade unions, political parties and the many economic lobbies, illustrates first the fact that the framework within which important political decisions are taken is not identical with the state and its central organs, and secondly, how closely bound politics and the economy are. This can also be seen in the fact that between two-thirds and three-quarters of the non-socialist members of parliament are at the same time on the board of directors of important firms in the industrial or services sectors. Thus these companies are in constant and direct contact with the political scene. Let us now consider how the structure of Switzerland's political system takes into account the conflicts and problems arising in other areas of its social structure. In simple terms one can say that two basic conflicts are especially well "catered for", both of them centering around typical, historical inequality in Swiss society. The first is that between federalism and centralism, which is based on the centuries-old inequality between the cantons, and the second is that between labour and capital, which took on a more important aspect in particular at the turn of the century. To say that these two conflicts are well taken into account within the political system does not mean that the problems have been solved, but that committees and procedures have been set up whereby the representatives of the most important groups affected by a certain problem can have their say and exercise a certain amount of influence. One of the most important dispositions in this respect is the consultation system, by which before any important political decision is taken all the interested parties, as well as the cantons and the political parties, are consulted. The principle of "democracy by agreement", which aims at balancing out the difference in interests, has a strong influence on most of the other committees and procedures. Thus, for example, the most important lobbies are represented in the so-called panels of experts, with the result that the suggestions they make are already in fact political compromises before they go through the consultation procedure, official processes and parliamentary debate. In this case the attitude taken is influenced mainly by the "fighting strength" of the lobbies involved. One of their classical ways of making themselves heard is to threaten to demand a referendum on any decision which is not to their liking. In Switzerland there exists a "magic formula" to take into account the class problem. According to an agreement reached between the four main parties, the seven government seats have, since 1959, been shared out between them as follows: 2 for the Liberals, 2 for the Christian Democrats, 2 for the Social Democrats and 1 for the Swiss People's Party (farmers and the middle classes). Thus the political left has only a minority representation of 2 seats in the government, although according to the current principle applied in the government the Social Democrats carry the same responsibility as the 5 other (non-socialist) ministers. The most important example of official allowances being made for the problems arising from federalism is the system by which bills and initiatives or referendums are passed. In order for a bill to be successful it must be passed by a majority vote in both Houses; an initiative or a referendum must be accepted by the majority of the voters as a whole and by the majority of cantons, the same votes being counted to give a result for each canton. In recent years it has occasionally happened that important bills have been accepted by the majority of the voters who live in the industrialised cantons and in the towns, but have been thwarted by a majority of negative-voting, low population cantons. If one compares the two "institutionalised" points of conflict with the list of structural changes which have taken place, especially in the economy and in employment, it is easy to think that the structure of the political system reflects more strongly the problems of the 19th century, i.e. of the period when the system was born, than those of more recent times. We shall go back to this supposition in Chapter 6. e) Social Sectors and the Exercise of Power Through the examples of education, the economy and politics we have shown in this chapter how social assets and individual standard of living are dependent on the more comprehensive organisation of society. In all three fields characteristics of structure and historical development were exposed, which are of far-reaching importance in the life of the individual in Switzerland and which cannot be automatically influenced by him. One of the most important trends and structural characteristics is the increasing social division and the sub-division of each social sector into hierarchical and specialised categories. The consequence of this trend is that for most people their sphere of personal experience is becoming more individual because the various ways of belonging to social sectors comprise different factors for each individual. For this reason it is becoming increasingly difficult to discover that one shares certain problems with someone else, and there is a stronger tendency to look for the root of one's discontentment within oneself. In addition, the framework within which the individual gains his experience, in particular in his career but also in the political or consumer field, is broadening, while the social decision-making power is being centralised to such an extent that the individual will rarely be directly aware of it. We have been able to find various examples of this concentration trend in the economy and in politics. At the highest level of social decision-making there is a web of power, socially apparent in the uniformity of the powerful elite and organisationally apparent in the growing importance of employers' and workers' organisations. It is true to say that at the highest level of power it is not so important to distinguish between the different social sectors, as we have done so far, as several leading roles in politics and economics are often filled by the same person at any one time or in immediate succession. The decision-makers do indeed represent population groups with varying and even to a certain extent opposing interests. Through the fact that they are all leaders of their respective organisations and deal with each other in this capacity, they have many common problems, experiences and aims. By analysing the three social sectors education, the economy and politics and the relationship between them we have become aware of important features of the social structure of Switzerland. The federal side of education, however, has revealed that our image is incomplete. We must now examine the municipal and cantonal structure of Swiss society.